The Autumn of Dictatorship: Fiscal Crisis and Political Change in Egypt under Mubarak

The Autumn of Dictatorship: Fiscal Crisis and Political Change in Egypt under Mubarak

by Samer Soliman
The Autumn of Dictatorship: Fiscal Crisis and Political Change in Egypt under Mubarak

The Autumn of Dictatorship: Fiscal Crisis and Political Change in Egypt under Mubarak

by Samer Soliman

eBook

$21.49  $28.00 Save 23% Current price is $21.49, Original price is $28. You Save 23%.

Available on Compatible NOOK Devices and the free NOOK Apps.
WANT A NOOK?  Explore Now

Related collections and offers


Overview

The Egyptian protests in early 2011 took many by surprise. In the days immediately following, commentators wondered openly over the changing situation across the Middle East. But protest is nothing new to Egypt, and labor activism and political activism, most notably the Kifaya (Enough) movement, have increased dramatically over recent years. In hindsight, it is the durability of the Mubarak regime, not its sudden loss of legitimacy that should be more surprising. Though many have turned to social media for explanation of the events, in this book, Samer Soliman follows the age-old adage—follow the money.

Over the last thirty years, the Egyptian state has increasingly given its citizens less money and fewer social benefits while simultaneously demanding more taxes and resources. This has lead to a weakened state—deteriorating public services, low levels of law enforcement, poor opportunities for employment and economic development—while simultaneously inflated the security machine that sustains the authoritarian regime. Studying the regime from the point of view of its deeds rather than its discourse, this book tackles the relationship between fiscal crisis and political change in Egypt.

Ultimately, the Egyptian case is not one of the success of a regime, but the failure of a state. The regime lasted for 30 years because it was able to sustain and reproduce itself, but left an increasingly weakened state, unable to facilitate capitalist development in the country. The resulting financial crisis profoundly changed the socio-economic landscape of the country, and now is paving the way for political change and the emergence of new social forces.


Product Details

ISBN-13: 9780804777735
Publisher: Stanford University Press
Publication date: 04/01/2011
Series: Stanford Studies in Middle Eastern and Islamic Societies and Cultures
Sold by: Barnes & Noble
Format: eBook
Pages: 224
File size: 2 MB

About the Author

Samer Soliman is Assistant Professor of Political Economy and Political Science at the American University in Cairo. An activist for human rights and democratic politics, he is also a frequent columnist in the Egyptian media and a founder and editor of Al-Bosla, a radical democratic publication.

Read an Excerpt

The Autumn of Dictatorship

FISCAL CRISIS AND POLITICAL CHANGE IN EGYPT UNDER MUBARAK
By Samer Soliman

Stanford University Press

Copyright © 2006 al-Dâr, Cairo, Egypt
All right reserved.

ISBN: 978-0-8047-7846-6


Chapter One

GROWTH OF THE STATE UNDER MUBARAK Follow the Revenue Trail

THIS CHAPTER AIMS to define the main parameters of the semi-rentier state in Egypt and to trace and analyze the course of revenues and expenditures in Egypt since the outset of the 1980s. The purpose is to answer two questions.

First, what factors account for the fluctuations in revenues and expenditures? The theory we propose here is that the level of state revenues sets the pace of public spending. When revenues increase, so do state expenditures, and vice versa. Official economic policy, be it interventionist or laissez-faire, has little effect on the volume of public spending. Its rise or fall is not the result of a decision.

Second, what factors determine the volume of state revenues? The Egyptian state derives much of its income from petroleum sales, Suez Canal fees, and foreign aid. These are essentially rentier revenues, and they have driven national fiscal policy since the 1970s. Without understanding the fluctuations in these revenues, it is impossible to explain the transformations in economic policy.

MUBARAK ANNOUNCES A NEW ECONOMIC POLICY

"Prosperity is at hand," Egyptians were told during the 1970s. Toward the end of that decade, President Anwar Sadat promised that 1980 would be the "year of prosperity," and in September 1980, the minister of the economy proclaimed that the era of prosperity had begun. The upbeat tones faded quickly following the assassination of Sadat on 6 October 1981.

On 6 November 1981, several weeks after President Hosni Mubarak came to power, the editor-in-chief of Al-Ahram confirmed that the economic crisis was severe. His editorial ushered in a new official rhetoric on the economy that would contrast strikingly with the rhetoric that prevailed throughout the 1970s. The new official discourse was inaugurated in an economic conference that Mubarak convened in February 1982. In his opening address to the conference, cited in Al-Ahram Al-Iqtisadi on 22 February 1982, the president explained that the purpose of the conference was not to make general recommendations, but rather to assess the state of the economy with an eye to formulating an action plan. The conference's general conclusion, as laid out in the closing statement, was that the government would revert to central economic and social planning and steer the Open Door policy toward production. As the secretary-general of the conference said in this statement, the process of liberalization had to continue, but there also had to be a drive to reduce consumption and increase production. He added that the government was keen to propel the private sector toward the productive sectors and would take all necessary measures to achieve this.

The new economic orientation triggered heated debate in the government and in the opposition press over the value of the Open Door policy. A major forum was the state-owned magazine Al-Ahram Al-Iqtisadi, which opened its pages to such left-wing economists as Fouad Mursi and Ramzi Zaki. In their opinion, the policy was a failure. Among the many reasons they cited, the most significant was that the policy generated consumerist tendencies and favored increased importation over strengthening the productive sectors, especially industrial production. Economic growth in the 1970s, they maintained, had been purely a consequence of the influx of rentier revenues, primarily from the Suez Canal, petroleum, and foreign aid. Egyptian capitalists, meanwhile, focused their energies on speculation and investment in quick-profit fields such as consumer imports and real estate construction. This entrepreneurial class made up the "parasitic sector" of Egyptian capitalism. In Mursi's and Zaki's opinion, the solution was to encourage nationalist capitalism by reducing imports (by increasing protective customs taxes) and, of course, by revitalizing the role of the state in production.

The opposing camp of right-wing economists took up the defense. However, even as they continued to advocate the Open Door policy out of principle, they had to acknowledge that it had promoted growth in the trade and financial sectors over industrial growth. They further admitted that it had encouraged a flourishing opportunistic entrepreneurial class that had come to form "actual power centers," as former Prime Minister Abdel Aziz Higazi was cited as saying, according to Al-Ahram Al-Iqtisadi on 26 April 1982. Higazi had been selected by President Sadat to head the government during the transition to a market economy.

The Egyptian intelligentsia concerned with economic affairs was thus unanimous in the opinion that the Open Door policy had to be reassessed and rectified. The difference between the right and left was over how to rectify it and to what degree.

It was not long before left-wing economists came to feel that all the work they had put into studies and preparations for the economic conference hosted by the new president had gone to waste. The president heeded none of the recommendations of the conference or, at best, adopted only the easy parts. But as partial as the regime's implementation of these recommendations was, the difference between its economic rhetoric and that of the previous regime was total. Under Mubarak, criticism of the Open Door policy was not only officially condoned but also actively encouraged. In addition, the government sought to boost both private and public sector industry. Toward this end it raised protective import barriers, lowered the interest rate on industrial investment loans, and, significantly, reduced taxes on industrial profits to 32 percent at a time when the capital gains tax in other commercial sectors was 40 percent.

These measures did, in fact, help stimulate growth in the industrial sector. The government boosted spending on industrial expansion in the private sector, and a greater share of private sector investment went into industrial activities, increasing from 15.9 percent in 1981 to 34.7 percent in 1990 and 45.9 percent in 1995. The share of industry (excluding the petroleum sector) in the GDP increased from 13.5 percent in 1980–81 to 18.1 percent in 1990–91. The new emphasis tangibly manifested itself in the rise of such industrial cities as The Tenth of Ramadan and Six October. It was also reflected in the decision on the part of a number of import magnates of the 1970s to turn to joint production enterprises with foreign investors. For example, Mahmoud Al-Arabi shift ed from importing Toshiba appliances to assembling them and manufacturing some of their parts, and the Abaza family turned from importing Peugeots to assembling them and manufacturing 40 percent of their components. These are two notable instances out of many.

Most of the growth of private and public industry in the 1980s, especially in clothing and automobile assembly and manufacture, was heavily contingent upon customs protection, which is to say upon government intervention aimed at keeping prices of imported goods higher than prices of their Egyptian counterparts. This gave both state and private capitalism the opportunity to dominate the local market and set prices that oft en exceeded those that prevailed in other countries at Egypt's level of economic development.

EXPLAINING THE SHIFT IN ECONOMIC POLICY: FOLLOW THE REVENUE TRAIL

A common way for new presidents to establish their legitimacy is to point to the economic problems bequeathed by their predecessors and to disparage the policies that created them. It was only natural, therefore, that Mubarak would begin his reign with the refrain of severe economic crisis. Most analysts in Egypt have tended to dismiss that refrain as little more than propaganda. Yet, the new official rhetoric in the early 1980s reflected a change from the Sadat era, albeit not as radical as Sadat's about-face from the political orientation of the Gamal Abdel Nasser era (1956–70). Upon coming to power, Mubarak, like Sadat before him, applied himself to the task that any new regime has to undertake if it is not going to rely solely upon the instruments of violence and terror. That task was to build his own sociopolitical base. To do this, Mubarak had to clip the wings of powerful business magnates associated with the Sadat era, such as Rashad Osman and Esmat Al-Sadat, so as to clear the way for a new set of business magnates entirely loyal to him. The other social class that the Mubarak regime could easily court consisted of government employees. They were deeply resentful of Sadat's economic policies, which had cast them down from the elitist status they had enjoyed under Nasser to a much lower rung on the social ladder. The new official discourse about the return to central economic planning and the major economic role of the state was intended to reassure and win over this segment of the public.

Nevertheless, the shift in economic policy stemmed from more than the exigencies of building the legitimacy of the new president. Mubarak would not have partially reverted to economic planning had it not been for the growth in state revenues, a trend that began in the mid-1970s (see Figure 1.1).

The growth of the Egyptian state apparatus was the irony of the decade of the 1970s. While the official discourse emphasized the conversion to a market economy, the centrally steered economy burgeoned. Undoubtedly, the rise of a new and very conspicuous class of capitalist entrepreneurs and a very ostentatious nouveau riche gave the impression that the private sector was taking over an increasing share of the resources from the public sector. The fact is that this did not occur during the 1970s. As more money flowed into the pockets of the rising entrepreneurial class and a segment of the middle and professional classes, state-controlled revenue sources poured even more into the coffers of the national treasury. Consequently, government control over the nation's resources increased. According to a World Bank study, public spending soared from 48 percent of the GDP in 1974 to 62 percent in 1981.

Despite the influx of revenues, the regime was still inclined to borrow and to demand more aid from abroad. One can not help but remark how similar this situation was to the era of the Khedive Ismail a century earlier. Then it was revenues from cotton that poured into the state's coffer as the extravagant khedive plunged headlong into debt. In the 1870s, the Egyptian debt crisis led to the system of Dual Control, whereby French and British commissioners took over the management of the Egyptian economy; in the 1970s, Egypt's creditors pressured the government into concluding an economic reform agreement with the International Monetary Fund (IMF). Signed in 1977, the agreement obliged Egypt to reduce the national deficit and reduce government spending. President Sadat complied; one of his first actions was to lift subsidies on essential foodstuffs such as bread, flour, oil, sugar, and rice. Egyptians awoke on the morning of 18 January 1977 to discover that the prices of the staples upon which millions of poor and low-income families depend had suddenly doubled. The popular reaction was instantaneous and powerful. Mass protests and violent rioting lasted two full days before finally being suppressed by the military and police. About a hundred people died, and several hundred more were wounded in the confrontation between security forces and demonstrators. The Bread Riots, as this uprising came to be known, marked the first time since the military coup in 1952 that the army was brought to the streets of the capital to maintain public order.

The Egyptian government was forced to rescind the new economic policies nearly as quickly as it had decreed them, delivering a debilitating blow to the economic liberalization program. The 1977 Bread Riots had a major impact on how the Egyptian regime would handle economic and fiscal policy. Their lesson was quickly grasped: Sudden and excessive reductions in public expenditures courted violent popular explosions. Henceforth, a slow and incremental approach to reductions became the economic scripture to which Sadat and then Mubarak would faithfully adhere. As it transpired, public expenditures did not decrease; they increased rapidly both in absolute terms and as a percentage of the GDP. What made this possible was the increase in government revenues from oil, the Suez Canal, and foreign aid, which had begun to flow into Egypt due to its much closer ties with the United States.

STATE REVENUES START TO PLUNGE

By the time Mubarak became president, the level of public spending as a ratio of GDP had risen to an unprecedented rate for a third world country. Figure 1.2 shows how Egypt compares with several other countries in this regard. The only Middle Eastern country to surpass Egypt in the ratio of public spending to GDP was Israel.

The powerful economic role of the Egyptian state in the 1980s rested on enormous rentier revenues. More than half the national income came from sources other than taxes. Figure 1.3 drives home how important non-tax revenues were in Egypt compared to selected third world and Middle Eastern countries.

Mubarak thus came to power at a time of a considerable surge in state revenues. Unfortunately, several years into his rule the revenue taps began to close. The collapse in oil prices played a principle role in this process. Although Egypt is by no means an oil-exporting nation of the stature of the Persian Gulf countries, oil is one of the most important determinants of financial fluctuations in Egypt. The prices of oil and energy in general do not only affect oil and natural gas exports; they also affect the yield from Suez Canal transit fees, which is heavily contingent on the oil trade.

As noted, Egypt was one of the largest recipients of foreign aid in the third world. These funds also began to decline in terms of their ratio to GDP, as illustrated in Figure 1.4, when the fiscal crisis in major industrial nations forced them to reduce levels of aid to third world countries. Simultaneously, the population boom and the development of the Egyptian economy reduced the effect of aid. Figure 1.5 depicts the declining trajectory of the rentier incomes derived from petroleum, the Suez Canal, and foreign aid.

Tax revenues also declined. More than a third of the government's yield from capital gains taxes comes from the General Petroleum Organization, the Suez Canal Company, and the Central Bank. As rentier incomes dropped, so did the taxes paid by these organizations. Figure 1.6 illustrates the downward trajectory of tax revenues in the 1980s.

Lower income should lead to lower government spending. While such an adjustment makes fiscal sense, it is a political tinderbox. Reducing government expenditures means reducing or even cutting off the flow of funds to persons and groups that have come to expect them. An authoritarian regime such as Egypt's that depends on handouts to secure its control over society has very little flexibility when it comes to tightening the purse strings. As a consequence, the national deficit began to soar to the point that Egypt soon had one of the highest deficits in the world, as shown in Figure 1.7.

(Continues...)



Excerpted from The Autumn of Dictatorship by Samer Soliman Copyright © 2006 by al-Dâr, Cairo, Egypt. Excerpted by permission of Stanford University Press. All rights reserved. No part of this excerpt may be reproduced or reprinted without permission in writing from the publisher.
Excerpts are provided by Dial-A-Book Inc. solely for the personal use of visitors to this web site.

Table of Contents

List of Figures ix

List of Tables xi

Preface xiii

Introduction 1

1 Growth of the State Under Mubarak: Follow the Revenue Trail 35

2 Changes in the Distribution of State Expenditures: Security Prevails 54

3 The Impact of the Fiscal Crisis on the Relationship Between Central and Local Government: Decentralization or Fragmentation? 76

4 From the Rentier to the Predatory State: Transformations in the Mechanisms for Generating Public Revenues and Their Political Consequences 97

5 The End of the Rentier/Caretaker State and the Rise of Egyptian Capitalism: A Fiscal Infrastructure for Democracy? 138

Conclusion 163

Epilogue: The Political Economy of Egypt's 2011 Uprising 171

Acknowledgments 177

Notes 179

Bibliography 191

Index 203

From the B&N Reads Blog

Customer Reviews