A Survey of Sustainable Development: Social and Economic Dimensions

Overview

<p>Perpetual economic growth is physically impossible on a planet with finite resources. Many concerned with humanity's future have focused on the concept of "sustainable development" as an alternative, as they seek means of achieving current economic and social goals without compromising the ability of future generations to meet their own goals. Sustainable development brings together elements of economics, public policy, sociology, ecology, resource management, and other related areas, and while the term has become quite popular, it is
... See more details below
Available through our Marketplace sellers.
Other sellers (Hardcover)
  • All (5) from $14.34   
  • Used (5) from $14.34   
Close
Sort by
Page 1 of 1
Showing All
Note: Marketplace items are not eligible for any BN.com coupons and promotions
$14.34
Seller since 2006

Feedback rating:

(62413)

Condition:

New — never opened or used in original packaging.

Like New — packaging may have been opened. A "Like New" item is suitable to give as a gift.

Very Good — may have minor signs of wear on packaging but item works perfectly and has no damage.

Good — item is in good condition but packaging may have signs of shelf wear/aging or torn packaging. All specific defects should be noted in the Comments section associated with each item.

Acceptable — item is in working order but may show signs of wear such as scratches or torn packaging. All specific defects should be noted in the Comments section associated with each item.

Used — An item that has been opened and may show signs of wear. All specific defects should be noted in the Comments section associated with each item.

Refurbished — A used item that has been renewed or updated and verified to be in proper working condition. Not necessarily completed by the original manufacturer.

Very Good
Great condition for a used book! Minimal wear. 100% Money Back Guarantee. Shipped to over one million happy customers. Your purchase benefits world literacy!

Ships from: Mishawaka, IN

Usually ships in 1-2 business days

  • Canadian
  • International
  • Standard, 48 States
  • Standard (AK, HI)
  • Express, 48 States
  • Express (AK, HI)
$15.78
Seller since 2005

Feedback rating:

(643)

Condition: Good
2001 Hardcover SIGNED AND INSCRIBED BY AUTHOR! Good Condition. Reasonable wear. Still very usable. Clean, mark-free interior! SHIPS W/IN 24 HOURS! Processed by DHL with USPS ... delivery for an average of 3-5 Day Standard Shipping & 2-3 Day Expedited Shipping! ! FREE INSURANCE! Fast & Personal Support! Careful Packaging. No Hassle, Full Refund Return Policy! Read more Show Less

Ships from: Alton, IL

Usually ships in 1-2 business days

  • Canadian
  • International
  • Standard, 48 States
  • Standard (AK, HI)
  • Express, 48 States
  • Express (AK, HI)
$47.99
Seller since 2015

Feedback rating:

(61)

Condition: Good
Buy with Confidence. Excellent Customer Support. We ship from multiple US locations. No CD, DVD or Access Code Included.

Ships from: Fort Mill, SC

Usually ships in 1-2 business days

  • Standard, 48 States
$53.85
Seller since 2015

Feedback rating:

(365)

Condition: Good
Possible retired library copy, some have markings or writing. May or may not include accessories such as CD or access codes.

Ships from: Chatham, NJ

Usually ships in 1-2 business days

  • Canadian
  • International
  • Standard, 48 States
  • Standard (AK, HI)
  • Express, 48 States
  • Express (AK, HI)
$53.85
Seller since 2015

Feedback rating:

(365)

Condition: Like New
As new.

Ships from: Chatham, NJ

Usually ships in 1-2 business days

  • Canadian
  • International
  • Standard, 48 States
  • Standard (AK, HI)
  • Express, 48 States
  • Express (AK, HI)
Page 1 of 1
Showing All
Close
Sort by
Sending request ...

Overview

<p>Perpetual economic growth is physically impossible on a planet with finite resources. Many concerned with humanity's future have focused on the concept of "sustainable development" as an alternative, as they seek means of achieving current economic and social goals without compromising the ability of future generations to meet their own goals. Sustainable development brings together elements of economics, public policy, sociology, ecology, resource management, and other related areas, and while the term has become quite popular, it is rarely defined, and even less often is it understood.<p>A Survey of Sustainable Development addresses that problem by bringing together in a single volume the most important works on sustainable human and economic development. It offers a broad overview of the subject, and gives the reader a quick and thorough guide to this highly diffuse topic. The volume offers ten sections on topics including: <ul><li>economic and social dimensions of sustainable development <li>the North/South balance <li>population and the demographic transition <li>agriculture and renewable resources <li>energy and materials use <li>globalization and corporate responsibility <li>local and national strategies</ul><p>Each section is introduced with an essay by one of the volume editors that provides an overview of the subject and a summary of the mainstream literature, followed by two- to three-page abstracts of the most important articles or book chapters on the topic.<p>A Survey of Sustainable Development is the sixth and final volume in the Frontier Issues of Economic Thought series produced by the Global Development And Environment Institute at Tufts University. Each book brings together the most important articles and book chapters in a "frontier" area of economics where important new work is being done but has not yet been incorporated into the mainstream of economic study. The book is an essential reference for students and scholars concerned with economics, environmental studies, public policy and administration, international development, and a broad range of related fields.
Read More Show Less

Editorial Reviews

Booknews
The concluding volume of the series summarizes 75 articles by contributors in many disciplines around the world, and published in journals or other anthologies. They cover perspectives, building blocks, and policies on sustainability. Full bibliographic citations allow readers to find the originals. Annotation c. Book News, Inc., Portland, OR (booknews.com)
Read More Show Less

Product Details

  • ISBN-13: 9781559638623
  • Publisher: Island Press
  • Publication date: 3/28/2001
  • Series: Frontier Issues in Economic Thought, #6
  • Edition description: 1
  • Pages: 448
  • Product dimensions: 6.22 (w) x 9.18 (h) x 1.32 (d)

Meet the Author

Jonathan Harris is professor of art history at the University of Liverpool. He is the author of many books, including Inside the Death Drive: Excess and Apocalypse in the World of the Chapman Brothers, also published by Liverpool University Press.


Read More Show Less

Read an Excerpt

A Survey of Sustainable Development

Social and Economic Dimensions


By Jonathan M. Harris, Timothy A. Wise, Kevin P. Gallagher, Neva R. Goodwin

ISLAND PRESS

Copyright © 2001 Island Press
All rights reserved.
ISBN: 978-1-55963-863-0



CHAPTER 1

PART I


Economics of Sustainability: The Environmental Dimension

Overview Essay

by Jonathan M. Harris

Serious consideration of sustainable development requires a rethinking of major elements of economic theory. The standard economic perspective must be broadened to take into account environmental and social perspectives. In this essay, we address primarily the environmental issues, then move to the social perspective in Part II.

To some extent, principles of environmental sustainability can be expressed in standard economic terms. For example, economic theory provides for the internalization of environmental costs, and natural resource economics recognizes the concept of sustainable yield in natural resource systems. But to consider the full implications of sustainability we need to look beyond these formulations to consider the social and ecological contexts of economic activity. This in turn leads to a re-examination of some of the fundamental theoretical frameworks of economics. Among the concepts that need to be reexamined are capital, valuation, distribution, savings, investment, and economic growth. As a result, both the categories of analysis and the policy implications derived from that analysis change significantly when we take sustainability seriously.


A Broader View of Capital and Production

Standard economic theory treats manufactured capital as the key to development, with some attention also to human capital (skills and knowledge embodied in individuals). Although natural resources are acknowledged as an input to the productive process, they are not an important feature of most economic models. In addition, the social and institutional arrangements that provide the basis for economic activity remain very much in the background. Economic theories of sustainability are based on a more expansive concept of capital. Viewing capital broadly as any stock that produces or contributes to a flow of output, we can identify four kinds of capital: manufactured, natural, human, and social.

Manufactured capital is what is ordinarily referred to simply as "capital" in most economic theory. Natural capital corresponds to what standard economic theory traditionally defined as "land"; the reason for the different terminology is to emphasize the essential productive role of this factor, and to broaden the concept to include all environmental functions. Human capital refers to education and skills possessed by individuals. Social capital is used to refer to knowledge and rules embedded in culture and institutions, such as the legal system or the concept of property rights. All four kinds of capital and essential to economic activity, although standard economic theory emphasizes primarily manufactured and human capital.

Manufactured capital is maintained and accumulated through investment. This process, of course, is central to standard models of economic growth. There is a clear and reciprocal relationship between manufactured capital and economic production: more capital makes it possible to expand economic production, and the devotion of a share of production to investment makes it possible to accumulate more capital. The relationship can be defined in mathematical terms, using concepts such as the savings rate and the capital /output ratio, and is easily amenable to measurement and econometric analysis.

Human capital is also fairly well represented in economic models of the labor market and plays an important role in modern growth models. The dynamics of natural and social capital present more problems, and these kinds of capital have received less recognition and attention from economists. Yet for true sustainability to be achieved, all four kinds of capital must be maintained at levels that allow both human well-being and healthy ecosystems.


Manufactured and Natural Capital

In the first article summarized here, Robert Costanza and Herman Daly set forth the basic conditions for the maintenance of natural as well as manufactured capital. They point out that neoclassical economics usually treats natural and manufactured capital as fully substitutable. If this approach is accepted, there is no particular reason to conserve natural capital so long as manufactured capital is augmented by a value equal to or greater than the depletion of natural capital. For example, it would be acceptable for a country to cut down its forests if the economic proceeds from the timber sales are used for investment in industrial development.

Even in the neoclassical perspective, however, the principle of weak sustainability is appropriate. A well-known principle derived from work by Solow and Hartwick (the "Hartwick rule") states that consumption may remain constant, or increase, with declining nonrenewable resources provided that the rents from these resources are reinvested in reproducible capital (Hartwick 1977; Solow 1986). In this approach, sustainability requires that the total value of the two forms of capital remain constant over time. El Serafy has pointed out that in order to assess this value, there must be a full accounting for natural capital depletion (El Serafy, 1993; also see article by El Serafy summarized below).

A strong sustainability approach is based on the idea that substitutability between natural and manufactured capital is limited. Rather, the two are seen as complements—factors that must be used together to be productive. For example, a fleet of fishing boats is of no use without a stock of fish. In the case of critical natural capital—for example, essential water supplies—substitutability is close to zero. While it may be possible, for example, to compensate for some water pollution with purification systems, life and economic activity are essentially impossible without access to water. The strong sustainability approach implies that specific measures distinct from the ordinary market process are necessary for the conservation of natural capital. It also implies limits on macroeconomic scale. The economic system cannot grow beyond the limitations set by the regeneration and waste-absorption capacities of the ecosystem.

Costanza and Daly suggest that a minimum necessary condition for sustainability can be expressed in terms of the conservation of natural capital. This policy goal leads to two decision rules: one for renewable and the other for nonrenewable resources. For renewables, the rule is to limit resource consumption to sustainable yield levels; for nonrenewables, the rule is to reinvest the proceeds from nonrenewable resource exploitation into renewable substitutes. Following these two rules will maintain a constant stock of natural capital. To maintain a constant per capita stock of natural capital also requires a stable level of human population, a factor that Daly has emphasized elsewhere (Daly 1991).

The rules suggested by Costanza and Daly for natural capital conservation are rough guides rather than precise theoretical principles. Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen, whose pathbreaking work The Entropy Law and the Economic Process outlined the dependence of the economic system on biophysical systems, argued that it is ultimately impossible to maintain a constant stock of natural capital, since all planetary resources will eventually degrade or be used up according to the Second Law of Thermodynamics (Georgescu-Roegen 1971, 1993). But at a more practical level he proposed an approach similar to Costanza and Daly's, reasoning that "the enormous disproportionality between the flow of solar energy and the much more limited stock of terrestrial free energy suggests a bioeconomic program emphasizing such factors as solar energy, organic agriculture, population limitation, product durability, moderate consumption, and international equity" (Georgescu-Roegen 1993; summarized in Krishnan et al. 1995).

The issue of conserving natural capital is part of a broader debate on reconceptualizing economic theory. Giuseppe Munda places the issue of natural capital conservation in the context of a contrast between the two economic paradigms of neoclassical and ecological economics. Whereas neoclassical environmental economics seeks to apply the categories of economic theory to the environment, ecological economics attempts to modify the conception of the economic system to acknowledge its role as a subsystem of a broader planetary ecosystem. In this view, standard economic approaches such as valuation in monetary terms can give at best only a partial view of reality. An analytical pluralism that takes into account social and environmental dynamics is essential to the ecological economics paradigm (Norgaard 1989, 1994). For an extensive treatment of the principles of ecological economics, see Volume I in this series, A Survey of Ecological Economics (Krishnan et al. 1995). Economic and ecological perspectives on sustainability are discussed in Common and Perrings (1992). A recent evaluation of issues in ecological economics can be found in the articles by Wackernagel, Herendeen, and others in Ecological Economics 29 (1999).

The social basis for the conservation of natural capital is explored further in the summarized article by Talbot Page. Page suggests that natural capital conservation requires specific recognition in law regarding the "standing" of natural capital as a social asset. He offers an analogy to constitutional law: fundamental social principles must determine the broad outlines of natural resource management. The sphere of "purely" economic analysis is thus limited to more specific decisions within this general framework.

The importance of social capital in natural resource management is evident when "marketization" breaks down traditional social institutions that have governed the use of common property resources such as forests or fisheries. In such cases, it is essential either to find ways to maintain the traditional common property management institutions, or to replace them with effective new institutions. Unfortunately, the development process frequently creates a situation in which neither traditional nor modern forms of social control over resources are effective, resulting in rapid and destructive resource exploitation.

Failures of social capital development are also at the root of many inequities and much human suffering in the development process. This is a central aspect of sustainability that is neglected in standard economic theory and only partly addressed in ecological economics. In Part II of this volume, we address issues of social capital and development in depth.


Intergenerational Equity

Sustainability is sometimes defined as intergenerational equity—ensuring that future generations have an inheritance of natural, social, manufactured, and human capital at least equal to that of the present generation. From the point of view of neoclassical economic theory, sustainability can be defined in terms of the maximization of human welfare over time. Most economists simplify further by identifying the maximization of welfare with the maximization of utility derived from consumption. This formulation certainly includes many important elements of human welfare (food, clothing, housing, transportation, health and education services, etc.) and has the analytical advantage of reducing the problem to a measurable single-dimensional indicator. But it is open to criticism as a serious oversimplification of the nature of human wellbeing (see, for example, Sen 1999 and Ackerman et al. 1997).

Using the neoclassical definition of welfare maximization, a formal economic analysis raises the question of whether sustainability has any validity as an economic concept. According to standard economic theory, efficient resource allocation should have the effect of maximizing utility from consumption. If we accept the use of time discounting as a method of comparing the economic values of consumption in different time periods, then sustainability appears to mean nothing more than efficient resource allocation—a concept already well established in economics.

One line of criticism of this reductionist approach to sustainability centers on the use of a discount rate to compare present and future costs and benefits. Discounting has been subject to numerous critiques on account of its present bias, especially as the time period under consideration becomes longer (see overview essay for Part VI and summarized article by Lind and Schuler in that section).

A simple example demonstrates the general point. At a discount rate of 10 percent, typically used for cost-benefit analysis, the value of $1 million one hundred years from now is the same as a mere $72 today. Thus it would apparently be justifiable to impose costs of up to $1 million on people 100 years from now in order to enjoy $72 worth of consumption today. By this logic, much resource depletion and environmental damage could be considered acceptable, and even optimal, according to a criterion of economic efficiency.

The problem is that by accepting the use of a discount rate we have implicitly imposed a specific pattern of preferences regarding the relative welfare of present and future generations. Howarth and Norgaard have argued that the use of a discount rate is appropriate for the efficient allocation of this generation's resources but is inappropriate when the rights of future generations are at issue (Howarth and Norgaard 1993). Use of a current market discount rate gives undue weight to the preferences of current consumers. This creates a strong bias against sustainability in the context of issues such as soil erosion or atmospheric buildup of greenhouse gases, where the most damaging impacts are felt over decades or generations.

To achieve intergenerational equity, we need some kind of sustainability rule regarding resource use and environmental impacts. The solution of what Norgaard and Howarth (1991) refer to as "the conservationist's dilemma" is not easy. By imposing a low discount rate for decision-making, we can place a higher value on the future. For example, with a low discount rate future costs associated with soil degradation or global climate change would be weighed more heavily. But at the same time, the use of a low discount rate encourages excessive current investment in manufactured capital (for example, the construction of large dams or nuclear power plants), to the likely detriment of natural capital. It is, of course, possible to use different discount rates for different planning purposes. But such an apparently arbitrary choice has little theoretical justification.

Michael Toman suggests that the issue may be resolved by recognizing that some issues can be appropriately dealt with through neoclassical market efficiency, while others require the application of a "safe minimum standard" approach to protect essential resources and environmental functions. He suggests that the criteria of possible severity and irreversibility of ecological damages should be used to decide which theoretical framework is more appropriate. Others have referred to this approach as the use of a "precautionary principle," which should supersede economic analysis when there is uncertainty about possible outcomes and large potential ecological damage is at issue (Perrings 1991).

The adoption of this reasonable suggestion would have far-reaching implications for economic theory and policy. Note the essential role of "moral imperatives," "public decision making," and "the formation of social values" in Toman's suggested decision framework. None of these appear in the neoclassical economic model, where markets are presumed to be the best resource allocators, and the occasional correction of a "market imperfection" the only appropriate role for government. Thus Toman is in effect asserting the importance of sustainability as a concept independent of standard neoclassical economic analysis, one that requires an explicitly normative and socially determined process of decision-making.

This represents a fundamental shift in the economic paradigm. Much as the Keynesian revolution validated the concept of government intervention to achieve macroeconomic balance, the acceptance of sustainability as a valid social goal places a new complexion on all policy issues concerning the relationship between human economic activity and the environment. Markets may be valuable and essential means, but they cannot determine the ends, which must be arrived at by a social decision process informed by different disciplinary viewpoints. This will require an unaccustomed humility on the part of economists, and a willingness to work together with other social and natural scientists.


Issues of Distribution and Valuation

The advocacy of intergenerational equity also has implications for equity and property rights in the current generation. It makes little sense to talk about equity between generations without acknowledging the great current inequalities of wealth and income. In terms of natural capital and environmental assets, many questions arise as to private and social property "rights" over these assets. Who, for example, has rights to genetic resources, fish stocks, forests, or water? These issues are interlinked with distributional questions. A more equitable distribution of income would have major implications for the use and conservation of water resources, since clean water is a major unmet need in many areas of the developing world. (In neoclassical terms, the "demand" for water is not an "effective demand" if people lack income to back it up.)


(Continues...)

Excerpted from A Survey of Sustainable Development by Jonathan M. Harris, Timothy A. Wise, Kevin P. Gallagher, Neva R. Goodwin. Copyright © 2001 Island Press. Excerpted by permission of ISLAND PRESS.
All rights reserved. No part of this excerpt may be reproduced or reprinted without permission in writing from the publisher.
Excerpts are provided by Dial-A-Book Inc. solely for the personal use of visitors to this web site.

Read More Show Less

Table of Contents

Authors of Original Articles
Foreword
Acknowledgments
Volume Introduction
Pt. I Economics of Sustainability: The Environmental Dimension
Overview Essay
Natural Capital and Sustainable Development
Environmental Economics, Ecological Economics, and the Concept of Sustainable Development
On the Problem of Achieving Efficiency and Equity, Intergenerationally
Economics and "Sustainability": Balancing Trade-offs and Imperatives
From Political Economy to Political Ecology
Green Accounting and Economic Policy
Are We Saving Enough for the Future?
Progress on the Environmental Kuznets Curve?
Pt. II Economics of Sustainability: The Social Dimension
Overview Essay
The Human Development Paradigm
Sustainable Livelihoods: The Poor's Reconciliation of Environment and Development
Markets, Citizenship, and Social Exclusion
Gendered Poverty and Well-being
Government Action, Social Capital, and Development: Reviewing the Evidence on Synergy
Good Government in the Tropics
Pt. III Global Perspectives: The North/South Imbalance
Overview Essay
Views from the Periphery: Encountering Development
Global Ecology and the Shadow of Development
Biodiversity: A Third World Perspective
Global Warming in a Unequal World: A Case of Environmental Colonialism
Lifestyle Is the Problem
Enclosing the Global Commons: Global Environmental Negotiations in a North-South Conflictual Approach
Pt. IV Population and Urbanization
Overview Essay
Government, Population, and Poverty: A Win-Win Tale
An Ecologist View of the Malthusian Conflict
Accelerated Resource Degradation by Agriculture in Developing Countries?: The Role of Population Change and Responses to It
People and Environment: What Is the Relationship Between Exploitation of Natural Resources and Population Growth in the South?
Population and Urbanization in the Twenty-First Century: India's Megacities
Mexico City: Our Common Future?
Reinventing Cities for People and the Planet
Pt. V Agriculture and Renewable Resources
Overview Essay
Food Security and Sustainable Use of Natural Resources: A 2020 Vision
Sustainable Agriculture
Environmental Risks Posed by Transgenic Crops
Population Extinction and Saving Biodiversity
Rocking the Boat: Conserving Fisheries and Protecting Jobs
The World's Forests: Problems and Potentials
Pt. VI Materials, Energy, and Climate Change
Overview Essay
Materialization and Dematerialization: Measures and Trends
Material Use and Sustainable Affluence
Balancing China's Energy, Economic, and Environmental Goals
Environmental Quality, Energy Efficiency, and Renewable Energy
The Costs of Climate Protection: A Guide for the Perplexed
Equity and Discounting in Climate-Change Decisions
Pt. VII Globalization and Sustainability
Overview Essay
Globalization: Threat or Salvation?
From Adjustment to Sustainable Development: The Obstacle of Free Trade
Ecological Distribution, Agricultural Trade Liberalization, and In Situ Genetic Diversity
Multinational Corporations and the Neo-Liberal Regime
Foreign Investment, Globalization, and Environment
Globalization and Social Intergration
Reconciling Economic Reform and Sustainable Human Development: Social Consequences of Neo-Liberalism
Impacts of Structural Adjustment on the Sustainability of Developing Countries
Pt. VIII Taming the Corporation
Overview Essay
The Corporate Accountability Movement: Lessons and Opportunities
Socially Responsible Investing: Doing Good While Doing Well
Corporate Social Responsibility
Toward a New Conception of the Environment-Competitiveness Relationship
Civil Associations and Toward a Global Civil Economy
Sustainability and the Accountable Corporation
Pt. IX Local and National Strategies
Overview Essay
A Theory of Government Intervention in Late Industrialization
An Idea Whose Time Has Come
From Class Struggle to Class Compromise: Redistribution and Growth in a South Indian State
New Strategies for Rural Sustainable Development: Popular Participation, Food Self-sufficiency, and Environmental Regeneration
African Development That Works
Challenges to Community-Based Sustainable Development
What Is Micro-Enterprise Development for Women? Widening the Agenda
Pt. X Reforming Global Institutions
Overview Essay
Alternatives to the International Monetary Fund
The World Bank and Poverty
Assessing the Impact of NGO Advocacy Campaigns on World Bank Projects and Policies
Coping with Ecological Globalization
The United Nations Environment Programme and the United Nations Development Programme
Conflicts of Global Ecology: Environmental Activism in Period of Global Reach
Bibliography
Subject Index
Name Index
Read More Show Less

Customer Reviews

Be the first to write a review
( 0 )
Rating Distribution

5 Star

(0)

4 Star

(0)

3 Star

(0)

2 Star

(0)

1 Star

(0)

Your Rating:

Your Name: Create a Pen Name or

Barnes & Noble.com Review Rules

Our reader reviews allow you to share your comments on titles you liked, or didn't, with others. By submitting an online review, you are representing to Barnes & Noble.com that all information contained in your review is original and accurate in all respects, and that the submission of such content by you and the posting of such content by Barnes & Noble.com does not and will not violate the rights of any third party. Please follow the rules below to help ensure that your review can be posted.

Reviews by Our Customers Under the Age of 13

We highly value and respect everyone's opinion concerning the titles we offer. However, we cannot allow persons under the age of 13 to have accounts at BN.com or to post customer reviews. Please see our Terms of Use for more details.

What to exclude from your review:

Please do not write about reviews, commentary, or information posted on the product page. If you see any errors in the information on the product page, please send us an email.

Reviews should not contain any of the following:

  • - HTML tags, profanity, obscenities, vulgarities, or comments that defame anyone
  • - Time-sensitive information such as tour dates, signings, lectures, etc.
  • - Single-word reviews. Other people will read your review to discover why you liked or didn't like the title. Be descriptive.
  • - Comments focusing on the author or that may ruin the ending for others
  • - Phone numbers, addresses, URLs
  • - Pricing and availability information or alternative ordering information
  • - Advertisements or commercial solicitation

Reminder:

  • - By submitting a review, you grant to Barnes & Noble.com and its sublicensees the royalty-free, perpetual, irrevocable right and license to use the review in accordance with the Barnes & Noble.com Terms of Use.
  • - Barnes & Noble.com reserves the right not to post any review -- particularly those that do not follow the terms and conditions of these Rules. Barnes & Noble.com also reserves the right to remove any review at any time without notice.
  • - See Terms of Use for other conditions and disclaimers.
Search for Products You'd Like to Recommend

Recommend other products that relate to your review. Just search for them below and share!

Create a Pen Name

Your Pen Name is your unique identity on BN.com. It will appear on the reviews you write and other website activities. Your Pen Name cannot be edited, changed or deleted once submitted.

 
Your Pen Name can be any combination of alphanumeric characters (plus - and _), and must be at least two characters long.

Continue Anonymously

    If you find inappropriate content, please report it to Barnes & Noble
    Why is this product inappropriate?
    Comments (optional)