BN.com Gift Guide

The Puzzle of Unanimity: Consensus on the United States Supreme Court [NOOK Book]

Overview

The U.S. Supreme Court typically rules on cases that present complex legal questions. Given the challenging nature of its cases and the popular view that the Court is divided along ideological lines, it's commonly assumed that the Court routinely hands down equally-divided decisions. Yet the justices actually issue unanimous decisions in approximately one third of the cases they decide.

Drawing on data from the U.S. Supreme Court database, ...
See more details below
The Puzzle of Unanimity: Consensus on the United States Supreme Court

Available on NOOK devices and apps  
  • NOOK Devices
  • Samsung Galaxy Tab 4 NOOK 7.0
  • Samsung Galaxy Tab 4 NOOK 10.1
  • NOOK HD Tablet
  • NOOK HD+ Tablet
  • NOOK eReaders
  • NOOK Color
  • NOOK Tablet
  • Tablet/Phone
  • NOOK for Windows 8 Tablet
  • NOOK for iOS
  • NOOK for Android
  • NOOK Kids for iPad
  • PC/Mac
  • NOOK for Windows 8
  • NOOK for PC
  • NOOK for Mac
  • NOOK for Web

Want a NOOK? Explore Now

NOOK Book (eBook)
$42.49
BN.com price
(Save 15%)$50.00 List Price

Overview

The U.S. Supreme Court typically rules on cases that present complex legal questions. Given the challenging nature of its cases and the popular view that the Court is divided along ideological lines, it's commonly assumed that the Court routinely hands down equally-divided decisions. Yet the justices actually issue unanimous decisions in approximately one third of the cases they decide.

Drawing on data from the U.S. Supreme Court database, internal court documents, and the justices' private papers, The Puzzle of Unanimity provides the first comprehensive account of how the Court reaches consensus. Pamela Corley, Amy Steigerwalt, and Artemus Ward propose and empirically test a theory of consensus; they find consensus is a function of multiple, concurrently-operating forces that cannot be fully accounted for by ideological attitudes. In this thorough investigation, the authors conclude that consensus is a function of the level of legal certainty and its ability to constrain justices' ideological preferences.
Read More Show Less

Editorial Reviews

From the Publisher

"The book makes a significant contribution to our understanding of Supreme Court decision-making and has many strengths. Importantly, the authors are the first to systematically tackle the puzzle of unanimous decisions captured both in terms of votes and the presence of separate opinions . . . [T]his is a well-crafted book that fills an important void in legal scholarship."—Eve M. Ringsmuth, Political Science Quarterly

"The heart of The Puzzle of Unanimity is an empirical study of all the unanimous and near-unanimous decisions the Supreme Court issued between 1953 and 2004 . . . And for those readers who come to this book believing that the justices arrive at consensus primarily because of determinate law or ideological convergence or strategic considerations or some other overriding causal factor, this book offers a powerful challenge to these kinds of reductionist assumptions."—Christopher Schmidt, H-Law

"This is the first comprehensive account of consensus building; it is imaginative and thorough and makes an important contribution to understanding the Court's internal dynamics . . . Highly recommended."—P. Lermack, CHOICE

"[A]n important empirical study on Supreme Court decision making . . . The variety of sources referenced results in a very rich bibliography . . . [T]he accessible writing and detailed explanations of the authors' methodology make this an excellent addition to an academic law library."—Tina M. Brooks, Law Library Journal

"In The Puzzle of Unanimity, the authors skillfully probe the sources of consensus on the Supreme Court and provide new insights on the considerations that shape the justices' choices. Their book is an important contribution to the understanding of judicial behavior."—Lawrence Baum, Ohio State University

Read More Show Less

Product Details

  • ISBN-13: 9780804786324
  • Publisher: Stanford University Press
  • Publication date: 5/15/2013
  • Sold by: Barnes & Noble
  • Format: eBook
  • Pages: 240
  • File size: 5 MB

Meet the Author

Pamela C. Corley is Assistant Professor of Political Science at Southern Methodist University. Amy Steigerwalt is Associate Professor of Political Science and Director of Graduate Studies at Georgia State University. Artemus Ward is Associate Professor of Political Science at Northern Illinois University.
Read More Show Less

Read an Excerpt

The Puzzle of Unanimity

Consensus on the United States Supreme Court


By Pamela C. Corley, Amy Steigerwalt, Artemus Ward

Stanford University Press

Copyright © 2013 Board of Trustees of the Leland Stanford Junior University
All rights reserved.
ISBN: 978-0-8047-8632-4


Excerpt

CHAPTER 1

The Roosevelt Court

The Critical Juncture from Consensus to Dissensus


The goal of this book is to explain consensus on the U.S. Supreme Court. A useful perspective from which to begin is to appreciate how the Court transitioned from a consensual to a dissensual body. We argue that this institutional transformation was the result of a series of internal and external changes to the judicial decision making process during the Roosevelt Court—a period roughly from 1937 to 1947 that was dominated by justices appointed by President Franklin D. Roosevelt. These developments—occurring both on the Court and in the broader political environment—fundamentally altered the dynamic among the justices and forever changed the way they decided cases. The end result was the replacement of collective expression—once the long-standing norm—with individual behavior. This chapter thus serves to highlight the central question investigated throughout the book: Given all of the institutional pressures that point toward dissensus, how are the justices ever able to agree? In other words, how do we explain the puzzle of unanimity?

Here we seek to explain why and how the modern era of dissensus began. To do so, we highlight what Pierson (2004, 55) termed a "conjuncture"—a moment in time when "discrete elements or dimensions of politics" collide to produce a new, and often unintended, effect. Specifically, we identify a number of institutional developments that dramatically altered the extent to which consensus could be achieved in the Court's decision making. We trace these trends by undertaking an extensive examination of the Roosevelt Court—the conjuncture, or moment in time, when its ability to achieve consensus changed.

Our investigation is based primarily on the private papers of Justices William O. Douglas and Harlan Fiske Stone, including memos sent between the justices, draft opinions, and other correspondence, which we use to determine the durable shifts in the Court's decision making processes during these years. Our analysis shows that various institutional changes instituted both before and during the Roosevelt Court affected the Court's decision making and brought about and entrenched a dissensus revolution in which individual expression went from virtual nonexistence to the norm.

While most scholars attribute the breakdown in the norm of consensus to Chief Justice Stone and his leadership style (e.g., Walker, Epstein, and Dixon 1988; cf. Haynie 1992), we break with them by highlighting the internal and external institutional developments that increased dissensus. More simply, to truly understand how the dissensus era arose we need to understand how the Court itself changed. By focusing merely on Stone's personal style, one might make the argument that another chief, with a different style, could return the Court to its previous levels of consensus. We argue instead that the institutional changes implemented during the Roosevelt Court so fundamentally changed the Court's operation that a return to the norm of consensus was virtually impossible.

Table 1.1 shows the important institutional developments—internal and external, cause and effect—that occurred during the Roosevelt Court era. As we detail next, once on the dissensus path, there remained only a "critical juncture" to fundamentally alter the institution (Pierson 2004, 134–135). That moment arrived with the conjuncture of the external intellectual force of legal realism, the largely discretionary docket created by the Judiciary Act of 1925, popularly known as the "Judges' Bill," and the appointment of New Deal legal liberals, including the elevation of Stone to chief justice, who brought with them a more open, academic style. Under Stone, the justices developed new internal practices that undermined long-standing norms and ushered in the modern era of dissensus. Conference discussion was expanded, opinion writing and opinion circulation delays became common, and there were frequent calls to reargue contentious cases. In short, an academic atmosphere took hold.

External and internal developments on the Roosevelt Court had a dramatic, long-lasting effect on both majority and minority behavior. Justices writing majority opinions increasingly departed from the views of the Conference, the norm of acquiescence broke down, and more concurrences and dissents were issued than at any previous time in the Court's history. Furthermore, majority opinions and concurrences were used to criticize dissents. Dissenters expressed small disagreements and discussed issues not raised in petitions, all the while praising each other for not acquiescing to the majority. The basic character of the decision making process was completely transformed.

The Roosevelt Court justices did not initiate these changes out of whole cloth. Specifically, developments toward the end of the consensus era foreshadowed the coming dissensus revolution. We propose that the consensus era on the Supreme Court began at the institution's inception in 1789 and lasted into the Hughes Court, from 1931 to 1940. Interestingly, it began at the end of the eighteenth century in a decidedly individualistic manner, with the earliest justices issuing their opinions seriatim (i.e., individually in each case), and ended at the close of the nineteenth century with a resurgence of individual expression, presaging the dissensus era to come. However, it is the period in between that largely defines what we term the consensus era. From the Marshall Court to the end of the nineteenth century, Supreme Court decision making was dominated by the institutional norm of consensus, including a desire for unanimity and a distaste for dissent and individual expression. Decision making took place orally; the justices largely acquiesced and said nothing publicly if they disagreed with the majority; institutional opinions were often delivered by the chief justice and not circulated to the other members of the Court for input (as they are today); and the practice of circuit riding provided justices with a regular outlet for individual expression. As Epstein, Segal, and Spaeth (2001) showed in their examination of the docket books of Chief Justice Waite, justices commonly muted disagreements expressed at Conference and instead joined the majority opinion. As a result, between 1801 and 1940, the Court handed down unanimous decisions approximately 90 percent of the time, if not more often (Epstein et al. 2007).

At the end of the nineteenth century, however, a number of institutional developments occurred that placed the Court on a path toward increasing dissensus. During the Fuller Court (1888–1910), the courts of appeals were created and the Supreme Court gained limited discretionary review over its docket, thereby allowing it to choose more important, and often more difficult, cases to decide. Also, circuit riding, the outlet for individual expression, was abolished. Now draft opinions began to be circulated to each member of the Court, and for the first time the justices were able to thoughtfully critique a written opinion before it was issued. These institutional developments helped promote dissensus and presaged the coming, modern era of increased discretion over dockets, the influence of legal realism, and further changes to the decision making process.

Figure 1.1 compares indicators of dissensus across consensus-era Courts. Although the transition from the relatively consensual Fuller and White Courts to the more divided Taft and Hughes Courts is evident from the percentages of dissents, concurrences, and cases decided by a one-vote margin, the levels of dissensus under Hughes were still similar to those under Taney. Thus, while dissensus was seemingly on the rise, there was no reason to believe that the Court would not soon return to more consensual levels. And yet, as we demonstrate, the justices of the Roosevelt Court so changed the way the Court functioned that even they appear relatively consensual compared to their successors.


Revisiting the Roosevelt Court

President Roosevelt made nine appointments to the Supreme Court, including the elevation of Stone to chief justice. Hugo Black, Stanley Reed, Felix Frankfurter, William O. Douglas, Frank Murphy, James Byrnes, Robert Jackson, and Wiley Rutledge joined Stone and the other holdovers to make up what C. Herman Pritchett (1948) termed "the Roosevelt Court." And while it is conventional to name Courts after their chiefs, we consider the justices who served with Stone to be members of the Roosevelt Court in this discussion, for it is this set of justices who transformed the Court from a largely consensual body into an institution where individual expression was common.

Figure 1.2 illustrates the dramatic sea change in nonconsensual behavior under Chief Justice Stone. While levels of dissensus increased during the Taft and Hughes Courts, there can be little doubt that the Roosevelt Court justices transformed the institution during Stone's tenure as chief (Caldeira and Zorn 1998; Halpern and Vines 1977; Mason 1956; Murphy 1964; Pritchett 1948; Walker, Epstein, and Dixon 1988). Nearly half of all Stone Court decisions had at least one dissent, nearly one in five contained a concurrence, and one in ten was decided by a single vote. No previous group of justices had ever come remotely close to these levels of public discord.

Figure 1.3 further shows that the dissensus trend ushered in by the justices of the Roosevelt Court was anything but an aberration. As new justices joined holdovers such as Black and Douglas, they adopted the dissensus norms begun by their predecessors. Dissent rates regularly reached 60 percent, concurrence rates continued to climb, to 40 percent, and cases decided by a one-vote margin reached 20 percent. Although the personal predilections of the holdovers certainly contributed to the growth of dissensus over time, a number of important institutional changes that occurred during the Roosevelt Court continued to be influential on future Courts and helped to entrench the norm of dissensus, which continues to this day.

Once the justices of the Roosevelt Court set out on the dissensus path, their practices and behavior only increased the amount of divisiveness over time. Figure 1.4 shows that cases with dissents reached an all-time high of 52 percent in 1943, only to be topped at 60 percent in 1946. This upward trend continued until 80 percent of the decisions handed down in 1952 contained a dissent—a record that still stands. Dissents were common among Roosevelt Court justices in landmark cases. These included Betts v. Brady (1942), in which Black, Douglas, and Murphy disagreed with the majority opinion denying a right to counsel for indigent defendants; West Virginia State Board of Education v. Barnette (1943), in which Frankfurter, Reed, and Owen Roberts dissented from a ruling protecting students from being forced to salute the American flag and recite the Pledge of Allegiance in public schools; and Korematsu v. United States (1944), in which Roberts, Murphy, and Jackson opposed the Court's decision allowing the government to intern Japanese Americans during World War II.

Figure 1.4 also reveals an increase in the percentage of cases with a concurrence, which climbed to another record of 31 percent in 1946. Eventually, the justices issued concurrences in 57 percent of cases by the 1970 term—an as yet unsurpassed high-water mark. Even some of the landmark cases decided unanimously contained concurrences. For example, both Stone and Jackson concurred in Skinner v. Oklahoma (1942), which invalidated state criminal sterilization laws; and Douglas, Murphy, and Rutledge each issued separate concurrences in the World War II Japanese-American curfew case Hirabayashi v. United States (1943).

Finally, Figure 1.4 shows that the percentage of cases decided by a one-vote margin reached an apex of 19 percent in 1944. For example, both the Free Exercise tax-solicitation case Murdock v. Pennsylvania (1943) and the Commerce Clause insurance case United States v. Southeastern Underwriters Assn. (1944) were decided by a single vote.

It is important to note that the Court's disagreements were not simply the product of a few justices. Figure 1.5 illustrates how each justice on the Roosevelt Court increased his level of dissenting votes over time. For example, Stone's dissents increased from 4 percent of cases in 1940 to 19 percent in 1944; Roberts's, from 19 percent in 1940 to 36 percent in his final year on the bench; Black's, from 9 percent in 1940 to 21 percent in 1946; Reed's, from 5 percent in 1940 to 12 percent in 1946; Frankfurter's, from 1 percent in 1940 to 23 percent by 1946; Douglas's, from 9 percent in 1940 to 21 percent in 1946; Jackson's, from 7 percent in 1941 to 20 percent in 1946; and Rutledge's, from only 3 percent in 1942 to a striking 30 percent in 1946. As the figure shows, the dissensus trend was plainly a collective enterprise.

Still, despite the unprecedented amount of dissensus occurring on the Roosevelt Court, the justices reached consensus half of the time and in a number of important cases. They spoke in a single voice in the "fighting words" case Chaplinsky v. New Hampshire (1942), the World War II "enemy combatant" case Ex parte Quirin (1942), and the Commerce Clause agricultural case Wickard v. Filburn (1942). These decisions illustrate that even on a fractured Court the justices could agree on some of the most controversial issues of the day.

It is plain from the data that the Court experienced then-unprecedented levels of disagreement while Stone was chief justice. However, the extent to which Stone was personally responsible for this discord continues to be debated; for this reason we discuss Stone's leadership and the personal and jurisprudential divisions among his colleagues. And, while we acknowledge that Stone's freewheeling style helped foster an environment in which conflict thrived, we illuminate a number of intra-institutional developments that further undermined the old-era norm of consensus, already threatened by the extra-institutional pressures of the discretionary docket, legal realism, and rapid personnel changes. Thus, the justices of the Roosevelt Court came together at a time when conditions for increased dissensus were ripe. We argue that it was ultimately these institutional developments, rather than simply the leadership style of Chief Justice Stone or personal feuds among the justices, that transformed the Court. Nevertheless, those latter factors certainly helped reinforce the institutional developments that entrenched dissensus over time.


External Developments: Discretionary Docket, Legal Realism, and Personnel Changes

Three important external developments were central to the breakdown of consensus during the Roosevelt Court: (1) congressional legislation that gave the justices a large measure of discretion over the cases they would decide, opening the door to more contentious issues; (2) the controversial intellectual ideas of legal realism—in particular the notion of law as indeterminate—that provided an environment for conflict to thrive; and (3) President Roosevelt's successful appointment of justices who were critical of their predecessors and therefore receptive to changing the institution both procedurally and substantively. In this section, we briefly address how each influenced the Court's decision making processes. Without these crucial developments, the justices would have had neither the incentive nor the opportunity to undermine consensual norms or to create internal procedures conducive to dissensus to the extent that they did.


Trifling Cases: The Judges' Bill of 1925

The Judges' Bill of 1925 eliminated the vast majority of mandatory appeals and allowed the Court to choose which certiorari petitions it would consider. This was perhaps the most important development of the Taft Court. Relieving the justices of their burdensome mandatory docket allowed them to focus on the most significant, and usually most contentious, issues of the day, and the implications of this for the decline of consensual decision making cannot be overstated. In short, the justices no longer faced large numbers of relatively easy cases on which they could all agree. Consider the comments of Justice John H. Clarke in his 1922 resignation letter to President Wilson:

Much more than ½ the cases are of no considerable importance whether considered from the point of view of the principles or of the property involved in them, but, nevertheless, a conscientious judge writing them must master details with the utmost care. My theory of writing opinions has always been that if clearly stated 9 cases out of 10 will decide themselves,—what the decision should be will emerge from the statement of the facts as certainly as the issues will.... I protested often, but in vain, that too many trifling cases were being written, that our strength should be conserved for better things. (quoted in Post 2001, 22–23)


Some have dismissed Clark's remarks as the product of personal melancholy over his sister's death; however, Justice George Sutherland made similar comments. In his Senate testimony in favor of the Act, Sutherland explained that "a very large proportion of the cases that come" to the Court "ought never to be there at all" and that the justices were burdened by "a large number of trifling cases" (Post 2001, 23).

The Judges' Bill greatly limited the types of cases granted a mandatory appeal to the Supreme Court. With this reduction of its mandatory jurisdiction, the Court could focus more attention on deciding important constitutional and statutory questions, and spend less time on routine appeals cases.

Not surprisingly, the justices increasingly chose to adjudicate cases containing difficult and complex legal issues of national importance—namely, those involving civil rights and liberties. Cases involving freedom of speech, religious liberty, privacy, the rights of the accused, and race and sex discrimination not only became a permanent feature of the annual caseload but also divided the justices as never before. Indeed, even the New Deal liberal justices appointed by Franklin Roosevelt differed on these and other matters. The establishment of the Supreme Court's discretionary docket was thus a key external development that helped usher in a new era of dissensus.
(Continues...)


Excerpted from The Puzzle of Unanimity by Pamela C. Corley. Copyright © 2013 by Board of Trustees of the Leland Stanford Junior University. Excerpted by permission of STANFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS.
All rights reserved. No part of this excerpt may be reproduced or reprinted without permission in writing from the publisher.
Excerpts are provided by Dial-A-Book Inc. solely for the personal use of visitors to this web site.

Read More Show Less

Table of Contents

Contents

List of Illustrations....................     ix     

Acknowledgments....................     xi     

Introduction....................     1     

1. The Roosevelt Court: The Critical Juncture from Consensus to Dissensus..     14     

2. Closing the Jaws of the Decision Making Vise: A Theory and Model of
Consensus....................     49     

3. A Function of Design: Consensus in Votes on the Merits..................     94     

4. Monolithic Solidarity: Consensus in Opinion Writing....................     114     

5. An Opportunity to Clarify: Unanimity and Agenda Setting.................     141     

6. Conclusion....................     160     

Appendix....................     169     

Index of Cases....................     177     

Notes....................     179     

Bibliography....................     185     

Index....................     197     


Read More Show Less

Customer Reviews

Be the first to write a review
( 0 )
Rating Distribution

5 Star

(0)

4 Star

(0)

3 Star

(0)

2 Star

(0)

1 Star

(0)

Your Rating:

Your Name: Create a Pen Name or

Barnes & Noble.com Review Rules

Our reader reviews allow you to share your comments on titles you liked, or didn't, with others. By submitting an online review, you are representing to Barnes & Noble.com that all information contained in your review is original and accurate in all respects, and that the submission of such content by you and the posting of such content by Barnes & Noble.com does not and will not violate the rights of any third party. Please follow the rules below to help ensure that your review can be posted.

Reviews by Our Customers Under the Age of 13

We highly value and respect everyone's opinion concerning the titles we offer. However, we cannot allow persons under the age of 13 to have accounts at BN.com or to post customer reviews. Please see our Terms of Use for more details.

What to exclude from your review:

Please do not write about reviews, commentary, or information posted on the product page. If you see any errors in the information on the product page, please send us an email.

Reviews should not contain any of the following:

  • - HTML tags, profanity, obscenities, vulgarities, or comments that defame anyone
  • - Time-sensitive information such as tour dates, signings, lectures, etc.
  • - Single-word reviews. Other people will read your review to discover why you liked or didn't like the title. Be descriptive.
  • - Comments focusing on the author or that may ruin the ending for others
  • - Phone numbers, addresses, URLs
  • - Pricing and availability information or alternative ordering information
  • - Advertisements or commercial solicitation

Reminder:

  • - By submitting a review, you grant to Barnes & Noble.com and its sublicensees the royalty-free, perpetual, irrevocable right and license to use the review in accordance with the Barnes & Noble.com Terms of Use.
  • - Barnes & Noble.com reserves the right not to post any review -- particularly those that do not follow the terms and conditions of these Rules. Barnes & Noble.com also reserves the right to remove any review at any time without notice.
  • - See Terms of Use for other conditions and disclaimers.
Search for Products You'd Like to Recommend

Recommend other products that relate to your review. Just search for them below and share!

Create a Pen Name

Your Pen Name is your unique identity on BN.com. It will appear on the reviews you write and other website activities. Your Pen Name cannot be edited, changed or deleted once submitted.

 
Your Pen Name can be any combination of alphanumeric characters (plus - and _), and must be at least two characters long.

Continue Anonymously

    If you find inappropriate content, please report it to Barnes & Noble
    Why is this product inappropriate?
    Comments (optional)