Obsolescence: An Architectural History

Obsolescence: An Architectural History

by Daniel M. Abramson

Hardcover(New Edition)

$35.00
View All Available Formats & Editions
Eligible for FREE SHIPPING
  • Want it by Monday, October 1?   Order by 12:00 PM Eastern and choose Expedited Shipping at checkout.

Overview

Obsolescence: An Architectural History by Daniel M. Abramson


Things fall apart. But in his innovative, wide-ranging, and well-illustrated book, Daniel Abramson investigates the American definition of what “falling apart” entails. We build new buildings partly in response to demand, but even more because we believe that existing buildings are slowly becoming obsolete and need to be replaced. Abramson shows that our idea of obsolescence is a product of our tax code, which was shaped by lobbying from building interests who benefit from the idea that buildings depreciate and need to be replaced. The belief in depreciation is not held worldwide—which helps explain why preservation movements struggle more in America than elsewhere. Abramson’s tour of our idea of obsolescence culminates in an assessment of recent tropes of sustainability, which struggle to cultivate the idea that the greenest building is the one that already exists.

Product Details

ISBN-13: 9780226313450
Publisher: University of Chicago Press
Publication date: 02/12/2016
Edition description: New Edition
Pages: 208
Product dimensions: 6.00(w) x 8.90(h) x 1.00(d)

About the Author


Daniel M. Abramson is professor of architectural history and director of architectural studies at Boston University. Previously, he taught at Tufts University and Connecticut College. He is the author of Building the Bank of England: Money, Architecture, Society, 1694-1942 and Skyscraper Rivals: The AIG Building and the Architecture of Wall Street.

Read an Excerpt

Obsolescence

An Architectural History


By Daniel M. Abramson

The University of Chicago Press

Copyright © 2016 The University of Chicago
All rights reserved.
ISBN: 978-0-226-31359-7



CHAPTER 1

Inventing Obsolescence


Before Obsolescence

Prior to the twentieth century, conceptions of architectural time in the Western tradition prioritized permanence and gradual change. The past persists visibly in centuries-old monuments, such as the ancient Roman arch of Septimius Severus, illustrated by the famed eighteenth-century printmaker Giovanni Battista Piranesi (fig. 1.1). Nature and history worked their slow decay, the same picture shows. At the same time, human reuse adapted gently to the past, as we can see in the middleground, where the ruined Temple of Saturn is repurposed to mundane ends. And new architecture hewed to deep time as well. The seventeenth-century baroque church of Santi Luca e Martina, in Piranesi's background, features classical columns and a symmetrical composition, which echo antecedents from centuries before. Ruinscapes like these parade architectural continuity. Time proceeds slowly. The past endures. Even when the nineteenth-century English architect John Soane famously had his monumental Bank of England building pictured in an exhibition watercolor as a ruin, with its roofs and walls sheared away, he did so not to promote the value of transience but to underscore his and the institution's dream of immortal, Romanlike grandeur.

Aesthetically, classical design, the dominant Western tradition since the Renaissance, strove for ideals of fixity and permanence. The Italian theorist and architect Leon Battista Alberti, in his seminal fifteenth-century treatise, defined formal perfection as "that reasoned harmony of all parts within a body, so that nothing may be added, taken away, or altered, but for the worse." According to Alberti's prescription, a building was beautiful only when it appeared unchangeable and finished in time. Architects followed this vision for centuries. Constructions of permanent stone, like Santi Luca e Martina in Piranesi's print, are embellished with centralizing motifs, like temple fronts or triumphal arches, and framed at their ends by projecting stonework or columns. These conventions of centralized, framed arrangement embodied an aesthetic of symmetry, hierarchy, and completion, implying an eternal order in their very composition.

Temporal continuity and stability was valued beyond the classical tradition. Mid-nineteenth-century British medieval revivalists esteemed historical "development" — "continued, gradual, tranquil" change, explains the architectural historian David Brownlee. The Gothic revival philosopher and critic John Ruskin extolled the virtues of permanence. "Architecture is always destroyed causelessly," he proclaimed in The Seven Lamps of Architecture (1849). Other nineteenth-century observers, who accepted modernity more readily than Ruskin, still wished for traditional architectural endurance. "We are not like our fathers, building for a short time only," the American critic Mariana Griswold van Rensselaer wrote in the Century Illustrated Magazine in 1884 about modern commercial New York. "Their structures have proved but temporary, while for ours a life may be predicted as long as the city's own." Van Rensselaer acknowledged the explosive initial development of a modern city but wished to see it slowed down in maturity, returning to architectural longevity.

To be sure, impermanent structures had always existed. Festivals, pageants, coronations, and fairs throughout history stood just for a moment. Famously in Japan, the wood temples at Ise have for centuries been reconstructed identically every two decades. But Japanese material impermanence fixes permanent principles; each generation internalizes the religious and architectural lessons of the past. The buildings may be deliberately transient, but the goal is eternal values. Occasionally, a building type in history had to face up to modern-style obsolescence — rapid, continuous devaluation and supersession engendered by external factors of innovation and competition. Renaissance fortifications, for instance, had notably short lives owing to improved siege technology. But this was unusual. Durability was the norm in building and values. It was only in the twentieth century that obsolescence became understood as a universal condition of built environment change — permanent and ceaseless replacement of structures and habits, applicable to all building types, regardless of function, form, and cultural meaning.

Another historical antecedent of modern obsolescence might perhaps be found in past large-scale urban renewals caused by natural disaster, war, or politics. The famous mid-nineteenth-century redevelopment of Paris, led by Baron Georges-Eugène Haussmann, impelled the poet Charles Baudelaire at the time to lament, "Alas, a city's face changes faster than the heart of a mortal." But no one at the time envisioned Haussmann's redevelopment to be endless, rebuilt again and again, ad infinitum. Only in the twentieth century did a pace of unending, ceaseless change in the built environment come to be understood as the new normal.

In nineteenth-century culture the possibility of permanently shortened building lives and cultural values was recognized but not yet accepted as a desired end. Nathaniel Hawthorne in The House of the Seven Gables (1851) has the youthful "wild reformer" Holgrave declare provocatively, "It were better that [our public edifices] should crumble to ruin, once in twenty years, or thereabouts, as a hint to the people to examine into and reform the institutions which they symbolize." Fixed building lives would reflect and impel radical change in each generation, Holgrave prophesies. By novel's end, however, Holgrave has reversed himself. He admits that "the happy man inevitably confines himself within ancient limits." And he imagines that he himself would "build a house for another generation" (emphasis added), not a short-life building.

The romantic ideal — invented in the nineteenth century and ultimately disavowed by Holgrave — that each age produces its own architecture was influentially voiced in France by Victor Hugo. "This Will Kill That," reads a famous chapter title in Hugo's novel Notre-Dame de Paris (1831), one technology superseding another. He hypothesized that the printed page had replaced architecture in the fifteenth century as "the principal register of mankind." In Hugo's time, some contemporary structures did appear to satisfy the desire to express architecturally the industrial character of the age. But spectacles like the vast 1851 Crystal Palace glass-and-iron exhibition pavilion in London were not considered proper architecture precisely because of their evident impermanence, even as they housed and embodied the latest marvels of machine civilization. Other aspects of the nineteenth-century Industrial Revolution did indirectly inspire the idea of architectural obsolescence and can be credited more directly with increasing the pace and scope of creative destruction generally.

The quickening business world, especially the cutting-edge railroad industry, which involved ever more people, goods, information, equipment, and capital, took an increasingly "deep and vested interest in a rigorous definition and measurement of time," explains the geographer David Harvey. From this arose a new class of professional experts, including engineers, economists, and accountants, who sought to master not just space and nature, but that key factor in industrial productivity and profit management, time itself. Time's effect on value was of particular concern to modern accounting. By 1840, historians report, "the concept of depreciation was widely known and the need to recognize wear and tear explicitly discussed in publications available to British and U.S. textile mill owners and managers." Assessing financial losses due to material wear and tear allowed industrial enterprises to value more accurately their capital assets for taxation, financing, and sale purposes, taking into consideration the dimension of time. Depreciation thus represented "a rational tool for management facing diversity and complexity."

Obsolescence emerged alongside depreciation as a financial risk management tool. Yet whereas depreciation resulted from slow, more or less predictable, physical wear and tear, obsolescence was different. It "was the loss which is constantly arising from the superseding of machines before they are worn out, by others of a new and better construction," said Karl Marx, citing an 1862 English source. He called this process "moral depreciation," but the more common term was obsolescence, from the Latin obsolescere (to grow old). The term was used first in sixteenth-century England to describe human speech "growne out of use," then in the nineteenth century to describe an organism's loss of function, before also encompassing inanimate machinery's loss of utility. In this newly understood process an object's material integrity holds fast — it is still young and operates as intended — but its functional worth has declined. Something better has come along to devalue and supersede it, to make it expendable and disposable. By the early twentieth century the accounting distinction between depreciation and obsolescence was well established. "Depreciation in its narrow sense, is physical — obsolescence economic," defined the real estate taxation expert Joseph Hall in 1925.

In architecture, application of the idea of physical depreciation emerged in late nineteenth-century America as a product of insurance and builders' estimates. The popular 1895 Architect's and Builder's Pocket-Book, by Frank E. Kidder, in its twelfth edition offered readers detailed life-span charts for a whole range of structures and materials, from frame to brick, dwelling to store, plaster to porches, with paint the shortest-lived component (five years) and sheathing the longest (fifty). The basis for these charts was an 1879 fire underwriter's paper, which in turn was founded upon eighty-three builders' reports from eleven western states. But economic obsolescence distinct from physical depreciation did not factor into Kidder's life-span numbers, which were simply material wear-and-tear rates.

Before 1900 the notion of obsolescence was thus absent from architectural thought. Buildings were expected to last for generations, along with the values and habits they embodied. Structures might wear out, but that process was slow, regular, and remediable. Rapid urban change might occur at one moment, but redevelopment would not be ceaseless. No one imagined a state of permanent expendability in the built environment. That idea had yet to be invented.


New York and Reginald Bolton's Theory

The concept of obsolescence, in the English language, was first applied to the built environment around 1910. Lower Manhattan was the early epicenter for the invention of the idea of architectural obsolescence. In the 1890s New York property corporations began investing tens of millions of dollars in large new structures to accommodate the growing numbers of lawyers, accountants, bankers, managers, and other white-collar workers servicing the new corporate American economy. These tenants drove demand for the latest plumbing, heating, and elevator technologies. Their ever-changing desires had the effect of devaluing even the most recently constructed accommodations. The scope of the demand required new kinds of institutions and organizations to finance construction. Previously real estate investment dollars had been gathered from individuals or small groups. But big buildings needed big money. New joint-stock real estate investment companies collected capital through stock issues from scores of individual investors and came to combine under one roof construction, finance, and real estate, such as that of the United States Realty and Construction Company. Moreover, these novel development entities used the existing money markets to innovate mortgage bonds, in effect cutting mortgages up into hundred- or thousand-dollar increments to be publicly sold to even more investors, making it possible to raise for building amounts of money heretofore unimaginable. As the professional building manager Earle Shultz wrote of later, similar Chicago developments, "Replacement of old, obsolete buildings was made possible by the flood of money provided by the bond houses."

The result of all this cash and credit flowing into commercial real estate was intense market volatility. Growth and speculation hastened demolition and new construction. A boom-and-bust environment developed, with demand rising even as oversupply threatened investment values. The risk of catastrophic loss was profound, and as a result real estate capitalists faced harrowing unpredictability. This was the context then for the unsettling demolition of the thirteen-year-old Gillender Building in 1910 and the disappearance of numerous other short-lived commercial structures across the United States. As the author Henry James wrote in 1907, shocked upon seeing New York after years away, "One story is good only till another is told, and sky-scrapers are the last word of economic ingenuity only till another word be written."

In this seemingly chaotic economic and built environment there appeared between 1904 and 1915 several books by New York real estate experts whose purpose was to explain the dynamics of downtown commercial development to real estate investors, for whom buildings were "capital invested for the sake of income [...] essentially utilities," as the mortgage company executive Cecil Evers put it in 1914. The most comprehensive of these treatises was Building for Profit: Principles Governing the Economic Improvement of Real Estate, which went through three editions between 1911 and 1922. This pioneering work was authored by Reginald Pelham Bolton (fig. 1.2). Born in London in 1856, Bolton had come to America as a young man. He trained in civil engineering and specialized in elevator technology, writing a pamphlet on the subject in 1908 as well as other articles on office building construction. Bolton lived in the Washington Heights neighborhood of northern Manhattan, where he also conducted extensive archaeological digs, joined the recently founded American Scenic and Historic Preservation Society, and wrote prolifically on New York's colonial architecture and life in such works as Washington Heights, Manhattan: Its Eventful Past (1924) and Indian Paths in the Great Metropolis (1924). Immersed in new and old New York alike, Bolton endeavored in both areas to steer modernization while sustaining established values. In Building for Profit the particular problem was the "financial deterioration" or "financial decay" of commercial architecture — what Bolton called, just once in his book, "obsolescence."

Bolton listed his ideas about obsolescence's causes, all extrinsic to a structure's physical condition. Among these were "the influence of fashion, change of habit, competition, development of new territory and shifting of the centres of population and business, altering of lines of transit." Each individually was unpredictable, its particulars uncertain, full of chance and risk, in a word (though not his), contingent. But Bolton was certain that obsolescence would happen in the built environment, produced by large-scale urban change. Population growth, social transformations, technical innovations, and market competition — all these would inevitably work together to degrade properties' utility and value, leading to early demolitions and ceaseless rebuilding. Modern cities, Bolton hypothesized, would predictably renew themselves, a "process of reconstruction occurring about three times in a century." Bolton's theory synthesized chance and regularity; the conditions under which this renewal would vary, but it would happen.

Bolton also proposed a theory of differential obsolescence. In a table titled "Economic Existence of Buildings," he ranked structures of various functions by "life in years," based upon projected changes in use, technology, and fashion (fig. 1.3). The longest-lived, banks, received forty-four to fifty years, offices twenty-seven to thirty-three years, and hotels fifteen to eighteen years. The most short- lived "taxpayers" (twelve to fifteen years) were one- or two-story buildings, the income from which could cover the taxes on a site until more lucrative development could occur. Bolton additionally tabulated physical durability, different than economic life, component by component — from sixty-six-year masonry down to seven-year paintwork — arriving at a hypothetical 48.36-year "mean life" for a steel-frame office building's total material fabric. These were largely theoretical exercises to encourage building owners to consider property in terms of time, money, decreasing worth and, ultimately, reinvestment and replacement.


(Continues...)

Excerpted from Obsolescence by Daniel M. Abramson. Copyright © 2016 The University of Chicago. Excerpted by permission of The University of Chicago Press.
All rights reserved. No part of this excerpt may be reproduced or reprinted without permission in writing from the publisher.
Excerpts are provided by Dial-A-Book Inc. solely for the personal use of visitors to this web site.

Table of Contents


Acknowledgments
Introduction

1 Inventing Obsolescence
2 Urban Obsolescence
3 The Promise of Obsolescence
4 Fixing Obsolescence
5 Reversing Obsolescence
6 Sustainability and Beyond

Notes
Illustration Credits
Index

Customer Reviews

Most Helpful Customer Reviews

See All Customer Reviews