Making the Chinese Mexican: Global Migration, Localism, and Exclusion in the U.S.-Mexico Borderlands

Making the Chinese Mexican: Global Migration, Localism, and Exclusion in the U.S.-Mexico Borderlands

by Grace Delgado
Making the Chinese Mexican: Global Migration, Localism, and Exclusion in the U.S.-Mexico Borderlands

Making the Chinese Mexican: Global Migration, Localism, and Exclusion in the U.S.-Mexico Borderlands

by Grace Delgado

eBook

$22.99  $30.00 Save 23% Current price is $22.99, Original price is $30. You Save 23%.

Available on Compatible NOOK Devices and the free NOOK Apps.
WANT A NOOK?  Explore Now

Related collections and offers


Overview

Making the Chinese Mexican is the first book to examine the Chinese diaspora in the U.S.-Mexico borderlands. It presents a fresh perspective on immigration, nationalism, and racism through the experiences of Chinese migrants in the region during the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. Navigating the interlocking global and local systems of migration that underlay Chinese borderlands communities, the author situates the often-paradoxical existence of these communities within the turbulence of exclusionary nationalisms.

The world of Chinese fronterizos (borderlanders) was shaped by the convergence of trans-Pacific networks and local arrangements, against a backdrop of national unrest in Mexico and in the era of exclusionary immigration policies in the United States, Chinese fronterizos carved out vibrant, enduring communities that provided a buffer against virulent Sinophobia. This book challenges us to reexamine the complexities of nation making, identity formation, and the meaning of citizenship. It represents an essential contribution to our understanding of the U.S.-Mexico borderlands.


Product Details

ISBN-13: 9780804783712
Publisher: Stanford University Press
Publication date: 04/15/2013
Sold by: Barnes & Noble
Format: eBook
Pages: 320
File size: 2 MB

About the Author

Grace Peña Delgado is Assistant Professor of History at The Pennsylvania State University.

Read an Excerpt

Making the Chinese Mexican

GLOBAL MIGRATION, LOCALISM, AND EXCLUSION IN THE U.S.-MEXICO BORDERLANDS
By Grace Peña Delgado

STANFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS

Copyright © 2012 Board of Trustees of the Leland Stanford Junior University
All right reserved.

ISBN: 978-0-8047-7814-5


Chapter One

From Global to Local CHINESE MIGRATION NETWORKS INTO THE AMERICAS

There was nothing in the lofty diplomatic career of Matías Romero to suggest that he would become a tireless advocate of Chinese immigration to Mexico (see Figure 1.1). Romero, a lawyer by training, joined the Liberal Party of Benito Juárez during the War of the Reform (1857–1861), when the influence of military leaders and the power of the Roman Catholic Church were replaced with a constitution-based civil society. In this period, Romero quickly climbed Mexico's diplomatic ranks. At twenty-five years of age, the Oaxaca native had already served as Mexico's chargé d'affaires and minister to the United States, where he tenaciously lobbied the Lincoln administration to arbitrate the French Intervention, in which France had invaded Mexico in 1862 under the leadership of Napoleon III. A dauntless proponent of liberalism, Romero facilitated U.S. investment in Mexico, earned the respect of Lincoln's secretary of state, William H. Seward, and engendered a close friendship with General Ulysses S. Grant. Romero proved equally effective as secretary of the treasury, offering, among many suggestions, that the United States assist Mexico in settling its debts with Britain, France, and Spain.

Neither Romero's extensive diplomatic résumé nor his trust in free-market solutions inspired the young attaché to turn to Chinese labor. In fact, Romero's plan transpired from his own frustration with growing coffee in Soconusco, Chiapas, which he pursued after poor health steered him temporarily away from politics in 1872. In his estimation, the tierra caliente, Mexico's tropical hotlands abutting Guatemala and Belize, held immense potential, but the region lacked a steady workforce to make coffee profitable. After all, Romero's ambition was not to provide Mexicans with the rich, aromatic drink, but to supply Americans with high-quality coffee beans, produced from the drudgery of Chinese laborers.

When Romero returned to politics as senator of Chiapas in 1875, he conveyed his plans in two essays that were circulated in Mexico City-based newspapers: Revista Universal and El Correo del Comercio. Romero's writings were consistently optimistic, appealing to the popular belief that where Chinese toiled in cane and cotton fields and filled mining and railroad camps, progress occurred. The former coffee grower stirred optimism that development was possible even in the most remote, most arid parts of the world. "It seems to me," he surmised, "that the only colonists who could establish themselves or work on our coasts are Asians, primarily from climates similar to ours, primarily China.... This is not an idle dream. Chinese immigration has been going on for years, and wherever it has occurred prudently, the results have been favorable." Enamored with China, Romero also added Japan to the mix of countries from which Mexico stood to benefit as a source for immigrant laborers.

If Romero's vision represented one possible pathway to modernity, it did so within a global context, one rich in international migration amid competing imperial and national worlds. Within this uncertain landscape, Romero pursued his conviction that the solution to Mexico's labor shortage lay across the Pacific Ocean. In 1882, an appointment as Mexico's minister plenipotentiary under the presidency of Porfirio Díaz finally afforded the physically fragile but politically stalwart public servant the influence to promote Chinese immigration.

Vigorous discussion ensued between Romero and a range of Qing Dynasty officials. Diplomats traded gifts: chocolate, rope from the fibers of the henequen plant, and Veracruz coffee beans in exchange for porcelain vases, tea, and cloth made from hemp. Eventually, Chinese laborers arrived in Mexico under official treaty protection, but not until 1899, twenty-four years after Romero first advocated for such immigration, and one year after the intrepid politician succumbed to an appendicitis attack. The delay in China-Mexico diplomacy was in no way due to a lack of effort or forethought on the part of Romero, who had distinguished himself as an astute observer of the mid-nineteenth-century world. The tireless immigration advocate could never, however, have anticipated the dynamic of overlapping empire-states and nation-states that would both produce and delay the very scope and manner of the arrival of Chinese into Mexico and its borderlands with the United States.

Opium Networks and Imperial Unrest

The complexities bearing on Romero's pursuit of opening up Mexico to Chinese immigration were a reaction to and emblematic of sweeping transformations occurring at the global, national, and local levels in the Pacific world at that time. Within South China and on its adjacent seas, the trading of British commodities and Spanish silver for South Asian opium established durable systems of illegal drug trafficking in the early nineteenth century. Decades later, these systems would evolve into trans-Pacific migration networks to facilitate the labor needs of transitioning imperial and national economies. After the 1820s, as Chinese, British, and American smugglers solidified mutually trusting relationships, the opium trade developed into a tightly organized cartel, the strength of which lay in the structure of its business alliances. To move the drug efficiently and into local and international markets, small, independent opium syndicates formed strong connections with experienced ship captains, who in turn hired large crews of men to help transship opium. The highly organized network also relied on the latest innovations in maritime communication and shipping technology, which made the smuggling of opium from India to South China and into Western markets remarkably efficient. Schooners arrived from Bengal at Kumsing Moon off the coast of Macao in May or June to transfer chests of "black-earth," "white-skin," and "red-skin" opium to Chinese intermediaries. Opium merchants then made their way into South China's inner harbors by collaborating with local sailors, who transported opium to their customers through the meandrous and narrow Canton Delta region using agile sampan ships. By late October, the selling and distribution of opium was complete. Schooners anchored at the harbor of Lintin, an island just north of Hong Kong, until late spring of the following year, when merchants and smugglers followed the same seasonal routine to acquire and sell opium.

Heu Kew, a subcensor in the Qing Military Department, described in frustration the scheming of opium cartels, which he was powerless to break: "The traitorous natives who sell the opium cannot altogether carry on the traffic with the foreign ships in their own persons. To purchase wholesale, there are brokers. To arrange the transactions, there are the Hong merchants. To take money and give orders to be carried to the receiving ships, that from them the drug may be obtained, there are resident barbarians.... And to ply to and fro for its conveyance, there are boats called 'fast-crabs.'" Within the taut, highly efficient organization of the trade, annual importations in opium rose gradually from two thousand chests in 1800, five thousand in 1820, and sixteen thousand in 1830, to twenty thousand chests in 1838.

The robust trading networks impressed many, especially those who were profiting from the cartel, but the durability and forcefulness came at a high cost. The strength of the opium networks sowed deep enmity between Chinese natives and British interlopers. Choo Tsun, a member of the council of the Board of Rites, expressed a common viewpoint: "The natives of this place were at first ... active.... But the people called Hung-maou [red-haired], came thither and ... in introducing opium into this country, their purpose has been to weaken and enfeeble the Central Empire." Repeated bans, the burning of pyres of opium, and harsh penalties for merchants, smugglers, and users failed to end the trade. Whereas the interests of opium smugglers demanded bonds of common trust, the Qing and British officials harbored deep misgivings for one another. For lack of a diplomatic tradition on which to draw and for want of a middle ground on which to meet, the far-reaching evils of opium led to war, and the status quo in China gave way to British imperialism.

The spoils of the First Opium War, as codified in the Treaty of Nanking (1842), bestowed British control over the ports of Canton (Guangzhou), Amoy (Xiamen), Fuzhou (Foochow), Ningbo, and Shanghai, and later eleven others, including Shantou (Swatow) and Qiongshan. The dealings of the British Empire with the Qing Dynasty proceeded from the conviction that the so-called treaty ports were, and should remain, bastions of unencumbered global exchange in order to benefit the Crown directly and the United States, Portugal, the Netherlands, Russia, France, and China obliquely (see Map 1.1). After the First Opium War in 1842, the emergence of Hong Kong and Canton as British-controlled treaty ports shifted commerce firmly into South China. Markets gradually reoriented southward from Shanghai, Hangzhou, and Wenzhou, while contraband trade in opium continued unabated.

Aside from a small number of merchants who applied their management skills from the opium trade to emigration brokering, few Chinese benefited from the new economic configuration. Dislocation and poverty caused by continuous war and village strife constrained the lives of most Chinese. Hong Kong, which was ceded to the British Crown in 1842, quickly acquired a reputation for unfettered commerce and as a hub for opium trafficking. The colony's 21,514 inhabitants—mostly native Chinese and British merchants and their families—seemed well equipped to handle the turbulence of legal and illegal market exchange, until British and Qing authorities called Hong Kong's status as a duty-free zone into question. With piracy going nearly unchecked in and around the colony, legal trade languished while illicit exchange in opium flourished.

In nearby Canton, the opposite blueprint emerged. Merchants from around the globe descended on the Guangdong capital city to trade and receive goods, paying duties on both imported and exported items. Hongs—Chinese franchised merchants licensed by the Qing emperor to trade with Westerners—mixed and competed with the thirteen European and American commercial houses on China Street. As foreigners and hongs prospered, Chinese boat merchants suffered the inequities of the new trade regime, and some fell into medicating themselves with "poisonous liquors" in the hovels of adjacent Hog Lane.

The terms of trade positioned the British Empire quite favorably in South China. British envoys worked alongside Qing customs officials to collect duties on imports and exports and to tender fines on wayward merchants. But as relations among Qing and British imperial authorities edged tentatively toward conciliation, efforts at accommodating post-war labor demands brought to bear old tensions from within and introduced fresh problems from without. Overpopulation, the shift to commercial agriculture, and export manufacturing displaced subsistence farmers from traditional landholdings. Cheaper British textiles drove Chinese clothmakers out of business, while many porters and warehouse employees lost their jobs when new treaty ports opened to export exchange.

Ethnic violence and civil war exacerbated the changing economic regime in South China. Commencing in 1851, the Taiping Rebellion claimed more than twenty million lives by 1864, when Qing forces quashed the advocates of the "Heavenly Kingdom of Great Peace." During the same period, the so-called Red Turban Rebellion divided loyalties between the Qing and anti-dynastic Triad organizations in the Canton region. More than one million Chinese lost their lives in battle, while the Qing army executed an additional seventy thousand Red Turban sympathizers. To make matters worse, ethnic tensions between the Hakka minority and the Punti majority plagued the Guangdong districts of Xinhui, Taishan, Kaiping, and Enping, known collectively as Siyi or the Four Districts. In 1855, Hakka claims to scarce arable lands set off a twelve-year clan war with Siyi residents, and thousands more Chinese died.18 British imperial control, ethnic violence, and the durability of the opium trade combined to create a national landscape in which migration became an ever-greater probability. Hundreds of thousands of Chinese would take up this path, voluntarily or not.

Between Slavery and Freedom: Migration Networks and Coolieism

The collision of the British Empire and the Qing Dynasty yielded to new arrangements of power that remade South China into a locus of transoceanic migration. The forces of rapidly shifting empire-states and nation-states and their transitioning economies configured transoceanic networks that were initially created from the early to mid-nineteenth century opium trade. In a little less than a decade, opium transportation networks matured to accommodate both the imperial appetite for semi-free labor and the demand for wage labor on the part of nation-states. After the British ended the African slave trade in 1807 and abolished the use of slavery in its colonies in 1833, plantation owners turned to Chinese and South Asian contract laborers. The switch to Chinese laborers supported the abolitionist claims of British authorities, and this strategy seemed to appease antislavery advocates. But the British commitment to rid its colonies of any form of slavery yielded to pressure from the Caribbean planter classes—mostly owners of large sugarcane plantations—to retain additional labor that was both cheap and tractable. Planters' profits fell precipitously after the so-called free-trade movement (1846–1849) equalized duties on foreign and colonial sugar. To restore the profitability of Caribbean sugar, British authorities turned to so-called coolie labor. The term coolie derived from the Urdu word quli, meaning "day laborer." By the eighteenth century, the term came to be synonymous with cheap South Asian and Chinese labor, whether imported or hired locally. However, by the mid- to late nineteenth century, coolie came to be understood as an indentured laborer, especially one who worked on a plantation. Coolie labor squared the needs of planters for tractable, low-cost labor with the conflicting demands of the British public for the complete abolition of slavery. The Spanish branch of this planter class, compelled less by humanitarian dictates than by a desire for profits in sugar, cotton, and guano (fertilizer made from bird droppings), exploited the British coolie network by adding Chinese to their existing force of African slaves.

Both the British system and the Spanish system worked in tandem with private individuals who held no national or imperial allegiances. The recruitment and transportation of coolies and the selling of contracts were in the hands of entrepreneurs or private firms operating within the logic of slave societies as French, American, Portuguese, Cuban, Peruvian, and British ship owners organized the coolie trade from both treaty and non-treaty ports. At Macao, Amoy, Swatow, Canton, and Hong Kong, migrant firms sold coolie contracts to Cuban and Peruvian planters at a far lower price than the cost of African slaves.

(Continues...)



Excerpted from Making the Chinese Mexican by Grace Peña Delgado Copyright © 2012 by Board of Trustees of the Leland Stanford Junior University. Excerpted by permission of STANFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS. All rights reserved. No part of this excerpt may be reproduced or reprinted without permission in writing from the publisher.
Excerpts are provided by Dial-A-Book Inc. solely for the personal use of visitors to this web site.

Table of Contents

List of Illustrations ix

Acknowledgments xi

A Note on Language Use xiv

I

I From Global to Local: Chinese Migration Networks into the Americas 13

2 Of Kith and Kin: Chinese and Mexican Relationships in Everyday Meaning 41

3 Traversing the Line: Border Crossers and Alien Smugglers 73

4 The First Anti-Chinese Campaign in the Time of Revolution 104

5 Myriad Pathways and Common Bonds 130

6 Por la Patria y por la Raza (For the Fatherland and for the Race): Sinophobia and the Rise of Postrevolutionary Mexican Nationalism 157

Epilogue 190

Abbreviations 201

Notes 205

Glossary 265

Bibliography 267

Index 297

From the B&N Reads Blog

Customer Reviews